December
1996
EDUCATIONAL
VOUCHERS:
EFFECTIVENESS,
CHOICE, AND COSTS
Henry
M. Levin
Stanford
University
December
1996 Draft—For Comments
Prepared
for presentation at Annual Meetings of the American Economics Association, New
Orleans, January 4, 1997. The author is a Visiting Scholar at The Russell Sage
Foundation, 1996‑97 and the David Jacks Professor of Higher Education and
Economics, Stanford University.
Abstract:
Most
of the policy discussion on the effects of educational vouchers has been
premised on theoretical or ideological positions rather than evidence. In
recent years a substantial amount of empirical evidence has accumulated on
achievement differences between public and private schools; on who chooses and
its probable impact on educational equity; and on the relative costs of public
and private schools and on a voucher system. The purpose of this paper is to
provide a summary of that evidence. (1) Present results among numerous studies
suggest little or no difference in student achievement between public and
private schools for a given student, but some evidence of higher rates of
graduation, college attendance, and college graduation for Catholic high school
students. (2) Evidence is consistent that educational choice leads to greater socioeconomic
(SES) segregation of students as the more advantaged have historically been the
families most likely to take advantage of choice. Families tend to choose
schools where other students are from higher SES backgrounds, resulting in
probable effects of rising inequality in achievement because of ³peer² and
other effects associated with high SES schools and the withdrawal of such
students from schools with lower SES students. (3) Despite assertions that
costs of private schools are considerably lower than those of public schools, a
comparison of costs in the Milwaukee Public Schools with private, voucher
schools suggests that the costs of comparable services at public and private
schools appear to be similar. But, the shift from the existing system of providing
public education through school districts to a market system of educational
vouchers would require considerable additional public resources for a
supportive infrastructure that would provide an effective system of choice and
competition. In particular, costs would rise because of public subsidies for
existing private school students, record‑keeping for each voucher
student, school monitoring, school accreditation, student transportation,
information systems on alternatives, and adjudication of disputes. Preliminary
estimates suggest an excess public cost on the order of $75 billion per year
nationally, about 25 percent of present spending, about $ 1,500 per year per
student.
EDUCATIONAL
VOUCHERS: EFFECTIVENESS, CHOICE, AND COSTS
INTRODUCTION
Since
Milton Friedman proposed his original voucher plan some four decades ago (1955)
with a wider dissemination in his important book on Capitalism and Freedom
(1962), the idea has taken on more and more credibility. Frustration with
public schools in the inner cities has been a particularly important reason for
emerging support of vouchers. Yet, both advocates and detractors tend to argue
more from theoretical and ideological grounds than empirical ones on the
consequences of vouchers. The purpose of this article is to consider empirical
evidence concerning three issues on which there have been strong views
expressed in the policy arena. (1) Will vouchers improve student achievement?
(2) Who will choose and what are the educational consequences? (3) What is the
evidence on comparative costs of public versus private schools and on the costs
of a voucher system?
It
is only fair in addressing these types of issues that I clarify where I stand
on vouchers. Almost thirty years ago (Levin 1968) I argued that the situation
of inner city students is so dire that we ought to be willing to design good
experiments with vouchers or voucher‑type mechanisms to ascertain their
effects on both individual and societal outcomes. In subsequent publications
(e.g. Levin 1980, 1987) I have argued that the specific design of a voucher
system with respect to finance, regulation, and information will be crucial in
determining specific outcomes rather than leaving the discussion at a generic
and abstract level, a point that is also stressed by Moe (1995) and Murnane
(1986). More recently (Levin 1991) I have suggested that the private benefits
of vouchers are likely to be positive relative to the present system in terms
of satisfying narrow consumer preferences, but the social consequences will be
worse because of greater inequality and the further deterioration of a common
educational experience as social goals of schooling are sacrificed to consumer
sovereignty. In what follows I will not take a stand on vouchers as much as try
to read the present evidence on the three issues set out above.
DIFFERENCES
IN ACHIEVEMENT BETWEEN PUBLIC AND
PRIVATE SCHOOLS
To
a large degree the arguments for educational vouchers have been premised on
whether they will improve the educational achievement of students, particularly
students from poverty backgrounds and inner‑cities where school results
are considered to be particularly woeful. Because student achievement is
considered to be a universal goal of schools, it has become the sine qua non
for evaluating school reform. We should begin this section by explaining how
limited this focus is in the context of market choice. The rationale for market
choice in education is to give families the freedom to pursue their own
educational preferences. For some families academic achievement will be the
prime goal; for others it will be a school environment that is safe and
supportive; for others yet it will be a quest for educational reinforcement of
religious or philosophic values. Although most families may have some concern
for the academic dimension, it may not be the prime dimension and may even be
overwhelmed completely by other school and family goals as systematic studies
have shown (Echols and Willms 1995). For example, in evangelical Christian
schools it appears that preparation for the Kingdom of God far outweighs
concerns about academic achievement (Peshkin 1986). So, comparing the
effectiveness of schools only on student achievement is not fully consistent
with measuring the impact of vouchers on educational outcomes where families
may choose schools according to many criteria. And, even as a measure of social
outcome, achievement tests are a limited and highly imperfect sample of the
range and depth of knowledge and skills, values, attitudes, and other behaviors
that we expect schools to inculcate in the young (Inkeles 1966).
Comparisons
of Public/Private Student Achievement
Nevertheless,
the primary focus in comparing public and private schools—even in the
absence of vouchers—has been to ascertain whether either sector has an
advantage in achievement, net of differences attributable to differences in
student characteristics. It should be noted that controls for self‑selection
are problematic in that even when controlling for race and indicators of social
class of students, families who choose private schools and make a financial
effort to pay for them are likely to be more educationally motivated than those
who do not. Therefore, we would expect students from such families to have
higher achievement than similar students who do not make the efforts to switch
from a public to a private school. Whether one can control statistically for
this self‑selection effect is problematic (Witte 1992).
The
first major study by Coleman et al. (1982) compared a cross‑section of
10th grade students in public and private (mainly Catholic) schools,
controlling for race and socioeconomic background. They found that students in
private schools had slightly higher achievement, from .12 to .29 standard
deviation units, depending upon the test. But, their results were criticized as
overstatements of the private school effects because of inadequate controls for
selection bias and other problems in the statistical design (Goldberger and
Cain 1982). Purported adjustments for some of these problems reduced
considerably or eliminated the private school advantages (Willms 1983).
Longitudinal
results based on sophomore‑to‑senior changes found smaller private
school advantages, from a range of no difference to .1 of a standard deviation
in achievement (Alexander and Pallas 1985; Haertel et al.., 1987; Hoffer et
al., 1985; Willms, 1985). This effect is statistically significant, but small,
amounting to only about 10 points or less on the Scholastic Aptitude Test for
college admissions, a trivial advantage. Further, it means that the achievement
overlap between the two sectors is so great that 46 percent or more of public
school students have higher achievement than the average private school student
who is statistically similar (Levin 1987:634). Using earnings equations for
1976 data (the achievement data were collected in 1980), such an achievement
advantage translated into earnings gains of less than 5 cents an hour for high
school graduates some 4 years after graduation and about 1 day less
unemployment a year among a cohort that experienced about 50 days of annual
unemployment.
More
recent statistical studies have also found no differences in achievement or
only minimal differences. The most sophisticated studies from a modeling and statistical
perspective are those of Goldhaber (1996) and Gamoran (1996). Goldhaber uses
the (NELS 88) data set and finds no difference in achievement between
comparable students in public and private schools (Goldhaber 1996). Gamoran¹s
use of the same data set with a different statistical technique, hierarchical
linear modeling, also finds no achievement difference or a very slight private
school advantage, depending upon which statistical formulation is used. In the
few cases where differences are found in favor of private schools, the
advantage is not even as large as the trivial differences cited earlier.
Even
when differences are found in such public‑private achievement studies,
they are often questionable. For example, Sander (1996) found no difference in
achievement between public and Catholic schools for students who attended
Catholic schools for 1‑7 years, but an advantage only for those who had
attended Catholic schools for 8 years. Not only is it puzzling that the
putative Catholic school advantage takes eight years to ³bloom² with nary a
hint of a bud in the earlier years, but even this result is questionable
because it is not based upon an equivalent public school comparison group. When
restricting the finding only to those who have attended Catholic school
continuously for eight years, it is necessary to compare achievement with an
equally stable public school group of students who have not been mobile. School
stability has been found to be an important correlate of school success in the
general literature (Rumberger and Larson 1996). But no attempt was made to
compare the achievement of students with 8 years of Catholic school (presumably
most attending the same school) with a comparable group of public school
students who attended the same public school. An appropriate comparison would
have been to compare students with the same stable attendance patterns between
the two sectors to net out school effects.
Another
recent study that models existing data sets to estimate effects of vouchers,
Hoxby (1996), finds that a statistical proxy for private school subsidies was
associated with both greater school competition and both higher private and
public school achievement, findings that reinforce the textbook version of
competition. However, as it turns out her model is based upon arbitrary
assumptions which, when relaxed, can yield exactly the opposite conclusions
(Kane 1996). That is, the results are not robust under a range of plausible
assumptions on model construction and interpretation.
The
Milwaukee Experiment
Of
course, none of the public‑private comparisons can be as instructive as
the direct evaluation of a voucher intervention. There are a handful of voucher‑type
mechanisms funded by private sources, but none has been subjected to a careful
evaluation of achievement effects (Moe 1995a). The only attempt to assess
directly the impact of vouchers on student achievement has been the Milwaukee
Voucher experiment. That experiment allowed students from families with incomes
no more than 1.75 times the poverty line to attend private nonsectarian schools
in Milwaukee with public funds. The numbers of participants were limited to no
more than 1 percent of Milwaukee Public School enrollments except for the fifth
year of the program when the limit was raised to 1.5 percent. Some seven
schools participated initially, rising to 12 in the last two years. September
enrollments in the private school program rose from 341 in 1990‑91 to 830
in the 1994‑95 school year, considerably below the maximum number eligible
to participate which varied from 931 in the first year of the program to 1450
in the fifth year. Attrition rates from year‑to‑year were
considerable, varying from 46 percent in the first year to 28 percent in the
fifth year, so relatively few students participated for three years or more
(Witte, Sterr and Thorn 1996:Table 1)..
Witte
and his associates compared student achievement and found no systematic
differences between voucher students in private schools and statistically
similar students in the Milwaukee Public Schools. Recently their findings were
challenged by Jay P. Greene, Paul E. Peterson, and Jiangtao Du (1996). These
authors argued that since oversubscribed schools had to randomly choose
students from their applicant pool, these conditions ³allowed for a natural
randomized experiment.² They then compared students who had been chosen to
participate with those in the applicant pool who had not been chosen. In short,
they found that private school voucher students in their first two years had
achievement levels that were not different from non‑accepted applicants
who were in the Milwaukee Public Schools. However, they found that voucher
students in the third and fourth years of participation scored higher than the
general pool of non‑selected students. They concluded that ³Students
benefit in measurable ways from the choice experience only after participating
in the program for three or more years (Greene, Peterson, and Du, 1996:13).²
Although
it can be argued that the students who entered the voucher schools were
equivalent for comparative purposes to the non‑selected students, it
cannot be argued that third and fourth year students were equivalent to the
control group of non‑selected students. In fact, attrition rates were
approximately 30 percent annually. Attrition students had lower test scores
than those who continued to participate in the voucher schools (Witte et al.,
1994, Table 1.8, p. 23). That is, consistent with the general literature on
school mobility, in that students who persisted in the same school were
superior to those who moved back to the Milwaukee Public Schools. The Peterson
et al . analysis, then, compares the stable group who persisted for three or
four years in the same school (superior in achievement to those who did not
persist) with all non‑selected students. The persistent voucher students
were a superior subset, not a random subset, of the original applicant pool.
Therefore it is invalid to compare them with the original non‑chosen
group and to conclude that the higher achievement scores of voucher students in
their third and fourth year were due to a schooling effect. In fact, it is
probable that Witte has overstated the comparative achievement of the choice
students in the third and fourth years by not providing a statistical control
for mobility to compare only with public school students who had been in the
same school for three to four years. A more elaborate analysis of this
comparison using instrumental variables and Heckman adjustments for self‑selection
finds no difference in achievement, and the ³effect² that Peterson, Greene, and
Du report is created by a dramatic loss in both numbers of students and
achievement scores of remaining students in the control group rather than a
comparative rise in achievement of those in choice schools (Witte 1996).
Differences
on Other Outcomes
My
own reading of the body of studies comparing student achievement in public and
private schools is that there is no difference for equivalent students or that
differences are trivial. In other respects there may be a private school
advantage for some groups. Although Sanders (1996) found no difference in
achievement between public and private schools for Hispanics and African‑Americans
with statistical controls for family background, Neal (1995) found that urban
minority students attending Catholic secondary schools have considerably higher
graduation rates than comparable public school students and higher college
graduation rates. He attributes these results to the particularly poor public
schools that are available to this group of students. It should be noted that
Bryk and Lee (1988) found that students in Catholic high schools are more
likely to be assigned to an academic track than in public high schools. Neal
estimated that the greater educational attainments of Catholic School minority
students in urban settings lead to earnings that are eight percent higher than
for comparable students in urban public schools. Evans and Schwab (1993) also
found greater high school graduation rates and college enrollment rates for
Catholic school students. Finally, as expected, parental satisfaction with the
schools their students are attending seems to be consistently higher for
parents of students enrolled in private schools relative to prior public
schools attended (Witte et al. 1995; Moe 1995a).
WHO
WILL CHOOSE AND THE EDUCATIONAL CONSEQUENCES?
Advocates
for vouchers believe that the advent of marketplace choice in education will
level the playing field by providing options in education for those who are
most disadvantaged by the present educational system. According to this view,
children from middle and higher socioeconomic families can choose to live in
the best neighborhoods with good schools or to send their children to private
schools. In contrast, children from poorer families are captives in
neighborhood schools in inner cities or rural areas without the ability to
pursue alternatives. If alternatives are provided, large numbers will use their
vouchers to choose better schools, requiring neighborhood schools to improve or
putting them out of business if they fail to improve. This view is reinforced
by the fact that surveys of poor and minority families show that they favor
choice even more than other groups (Lee, Croninger, and Smith 1996). But, such
a scenario assumes that the poor will take advantage of a choice system to
outflank their local public schools in behalf of better education for their
students.
In
this section I will suggest that the evidence consistently supports the following
conclusions. (1) Choosers will be more advantaged both educationally and
economically than non‑choosers, those who do not actively choose schools
for their students, but relegate them to their assigned school. (2) For
choosers an important criterion of choice will be the socioeconomic status
(SES) of other students where the most preferred schools will be those
enrolling more advantaged students leading to increased segregation. And (3)
both peer and contextual effects of higher SES students have positive effects
on achievement, leading to the conclusion that inequalities in educational
outcomes are likely to be exacerbated by vouchers.
(1)
Who Chooses?
Choice
systems may lead to two types of ³cream skimming². In the first type, families
who are better off may be more likely to take advantage of school choice than
those who are worse off because of better access to information, greater
ability to afford transportation, a higher penchant to exercise educational
alternatives, and greater generic experience with choice and alternatives. A
second type of cream skimming refers to the tendency of schools to seek and
choose students from families of higher SES and with higher previous
educational accomplishments(as modeled by Nechyba 1996 and corroborated empirically
in Belgium by Vandenbergh 1996). To some degree, the second of these can be
reduced through strong regulation requiring random selection among student
applicants, although both the political viability of such a regulation and its
practical reinforcement may be problematic. But the first type of cream
skimming, which is a consequence of voluntary choice by families, may be
endemic to educational choice systems as the empirical literature suggests. In
both public choice and voucher‑type systems it appears that those who
exercise the choice option are more likely to be of higher SES and to have
higher achievement scores than those who continue to attend their assigned
schools (Archbald 1988; Rubenstein, Hamar, and Edelman 1992; Martinez, Godwin,
and Kemerer 1996; Witte and Thorn 1996). Ambler (1994) found such cream
skimming in educational choice participation for both England and France.
Willms and Echols (1992) found the same to be true in Scotland as did
Vandenberghe (1996) in Belgium. Archbald (1988) and Moore and Davenport (1990)
found that magnet schools in the large cities that rely on choice to reduce
school segregation tend to attract higher socioeconomic students rather than a
random mix. Even when participation was restricted to families with incomes no
higher than 1.75 times the poverty level, parents of choice applicants in the
Milwaukee voucher experiment had considerably more education and parental
involvement than the average parent of children in the Milwaukee Public
Schools. In a publication on four private voucher plans in the U.S., Terry Moe
(1995 a), one of the most knowledgeable supporters of vouchers, Moe (1995b),
concluded that the problem represents a serious challenge:
Skimming is rooted in the calculus of choice
itself: in the utility functions of parents, the information they bring to
bear, and their income constraints. Some parents put a higher value on
education than others and so are willing to give up more to secure quality
schooling for their children. Some parents have more information than others
and thus know more about what schools are available and how good they are. And
some parents have higher incomes than others and so are better able to acquire
good information and afford good schools. Unrestricted choice, then, may well
lead to selection effects with a class bias (Moe 1995b).
Moe
concludes that such skimming can be reduced through restricting choice to those
who are most disadvantaged as well as making sure that voucher plans are
³Šsocially engineered through appropriate institutional design² to insure
greater social equity (Moe 1995b:24). Presumably such design features would
include more comprehensive and interactive systems of information as well as
adequate transportation within the educational marketplace. However, such
social equity features may have a high cost, an issue that is addressed later,
and it is not clear that society is willing to pay these costs.
Moe
concludes, correctly in my view, that the issue is not whether there is
skimming, but whether the skimming will be worse than the present public system
where students tend to be largely segregated in schools with students similar
to themselves (Moe 1995b: 24). Moe is also correct in suggesting that by
restricting the choice only to those most disadvantaged by the present system,
social equity would be likely to improve over the present system, although I
have doubts that political dynamics would support that solution over the long
run. But, what is the likely impact of a more extensive system of choice on
student segregation?
(2)
Impact on Socioeconomic Segregation
Many
observers have been concerned about the consequences for segregation of
educational choice. It has been argued even that one of the direct purposes of
choice is to increase segregation according to religious and cultural
differences to create communities of human capital through common ³social
capital² (Coleman 1988). Understandably, private schools tend to specialize in
market niches by creating differentiated rather than generic products in order
to appeal to clientele with particular political, philosophical, educational,
and religious orientations. This has been evident in Holland where publicly‑funded
private schools accounted for almost three‑fourths of all enrollment in
1980, and where over 90 percent of these schools were sponsored by religious
groups (Ambler 1994:468‑469). Surely this leads to greater religious
segregation than would be found if schools were based strictly on attendance
boundaries.
But,
to what degree does the fact that choosers tend to be from higher socioeconomic
(SES) origins lead to greater SES segregation of students? Since 1982 Scotland
has permitted parents to request public schools other than those to which their
students are designated by public authorities. By the late eighties about 9
percent of entering secondary students attended a school outside of their
designated areas with the numbers rising to 11‑14 percent in urban areas
according to sources cited by Willms and Echols (1992:340). By the early
nineties about 15‑18 percent of pupils in the most urban areas had
requests for other schools made on their behalf, with some areas experiencing
requests for more than 50 percent of students (Willms 1996: 140). Willms and
Echols (1992: 344) found that parents requesting non‑designated schools
had significantly more education and higher occupations than those who kept
their children in designated schools, as much as .35 of a standard deviation
higher. Average SES of pupils in the chosen schools was about .25 of a standard
deviation greater than in designated schools. Thus, choosers tended to have
higher SES than non‑choosers and to request schools with higher SES than
their designated schools. Willms and Echols (1992) conclude that this is a
major criterion of selection because higher SES schools tend to have high
achievement scores, although not necessarily high value‑added, which
should be a more central concern. But, high SES of the student body of a school
is easily observable, whereas direct measures of value‑added are not.
Overall the effect of this choice process was to increase student segregation
by SES of Scottish students between 1985 and 1991 (Willms 1996). In response to
Moe¹s (1995b) question on whether choice increases student SES segregation, the
answer in the Scottish case seems to be clearly affirmative. An analysis of
Belgium shows even greater student segregation under choice (Vandenberghe
1996), but this probably includes both types of cream‑skimming set out
above.
(3)
Consequences of Increased Segregation
Willms
and Echols (1992) proceeded to estimate the effects of schools on student
achievement and found that parents tended to choose schools with high
achievement scores and student SES, but not schools with high ³value‑added²
results after taking account of student intakes. That is, the superior school
³effects² were mainly due to a higher SES student body rather than school
effectiveness with a given group of students.
In
turn, it appears that increased student segregation by SES will increase
inequality of opportunity because aggregate SES of the school seems to have an
impact on achievement independent of the impact of the student¹s individual SES
on her achievement (Arnott and Rowse 1987; Link and Mulligan 1991; Henderson,
Mieszkowski, and Sauvageau 1978; Rumberger and Willms 1992; Shavit and Williams
1985; Summers and Wolfe 1977; Willms 1986). It is not clear whether this effect
comes from the influence of peers, school climate, or teaching conditions or
differences in teacher expectations and curriculum (Dreeben and Gamoran 1986;
Dynarski, Schwab, and Zampelli 1989; Rumberger and Willms 1992). Most of us who
teach will naturally raise the level of challenge if we believe our students
are well‑prepared than if we believe that they are not. At the same time,
students with high educational ambitions may create an atmosphere that supports
those norms among their peers. Whatever, the cause, the contextual effect of
SES seems well‑established. Further, it suggests rising inequalities in
achievement between students of lower and higher SES as they become
increasingly segregated in schools with students like themselves. As higher SES
students leave lower SES school environments for higher SES schools, their
achievement will rise. But, their departure reduces the aggregate SES of the
schools that they leave with a resulting decline in the achievement of the
remaining students in those schools. It is important to keep in mind that this
is a zero‑sum game because there are only a fixed number of high SES
student enrollments at any one time. Thus, not all potential choice students
can benefit from a high SES school environment, as it will be non‑reproducible
beyond a relatively limited number of schools.
Further,
the negative effects on low SES students are likely to be greater than the
gains of high SES students. The negative impact of segregation on the
achievement of students in low tracks (largely low SES) is not offset by the
higher achievement of students in high tracks (largely high SES) according to
statistical analysis by Gamoran and Nystrand (1994). This is also the
conclusion of Henderson, Mieskowski and Sauvageau (1978) whose results suggest
that overall achievement is higher in heterogeneous rather than segregated
school environments because any loss of achievement by the higher groups is
more than made up by the higher achievement of the lower groups. Summers and
Wolfe (1977) also found that less able students benefit more from this effect,
while higher ability students are less affected. Thus, if choice leads to
greater SES segregation, the impact on achievement will be to reduce aggregate
student achievement unless gains through school competition will offset the
achievement losses due to increased student segregation by SES. However, existing
empirical findings comparing public and private school achievement are not
promising in this regard.
Increased
segregation has other consequences as well, particularly on preparation of
students for democratic life. Effective participation in a democracy requires a
willingness to tolerate diversity as well as exposure to a common set of values
and knowledge. Research on political socialization has shown that tolerance for
other points of view is related to the degree to which different children are
exposed to different viewpoints on controversial subjects in both home and
school (Torney‑Purta 1984). It also requires a common core of experiences
to create citizens who can function democratically (Gutmann 1987: pp. 50‑64).
But, by segregating students to a greater extent than existing schools
according to SES, religion, and other dimensions, the exposure to diversity and
to a common core of experiences is seriously undermined.
COSTS
OF PUBLIC AND PRIVATE SCHOOLS AND A VOUCHER SYSTEM
Of
course, to economists and society it is not only the educational effects of
vouchers that should be considered, but also their costs. There are two levels
of costs in assessing the voucher alternative. First, there is the cost at the
school level. That is, for a given result in school effectiveness, what are the
relative costs of public versus private schools? Second, there is the public
(and overall) cost of the administrative and service infrastructure necessary
to support a voucher marketplace relative to the present system which is
considerably more centralized at both state and district levels. In this
section, we will consider what is known about each. Costs of Private Versus
Public Schools
Even
if private and public schools are about equally effective in producing student
achievement, observers have suggested that non‑elite private schools
entail considerably lower costs than public schools. For example, Peterson and
Noyes (1996) claim that Milwaukee voucher schools were receiving only half as
much for each student as the Milwaukee Public Schools. Therefore, they assert
that even if the voucher schools are no more effective than the Milwaukee
Public Schools, they are twice as efficient in the use of society¹s scarce
resources. A publication of the Cato Institute, a Libertarian organization,
makes the same point by comparing the tuition at private schools in several
localities with total per pupil expenditure in the public school system in
those areas (Boaz and Barrett 1996). This conclusion is also stated in other
publications that advocate a market approach to education (e.g. American
Enterprise Institute, 1978; West 1981).
But,
a comparison of public school expenditures with private school tuition is not a
valid approach to comparing costs. The problem is that the finance and service
mix of public and private schools is quite different. For example, tuition is a
much poorer proxy for the overall costs of private schools than is per‑pupil
expenditure as a measure of public school costs. Most private schools rely
heavily on supplementing tuition with fund‑raising events, special
student fees for extra activities, financial contributions, and in‑kind
contributions. In addition, those that are sponsored by religious organizations
(the majority of private schools) receive donated or subsidized facilities and
many Catholic schools are staffed partially by teaching clergy whose ³salaries²
understate substantially their true market value (Bartell 1968). The result is
that tuition charges cover only a portion of the overall costs of private
education. Although the public sector costs are not a complete measure of the
costs of public education, especially because of their treatment of capital
expenses, they are far more complete in comprising all of their resource inputs
at market prices than is the tuition measure for private schools.
But,
beyond this the service mix is very different between public and private
schools. For example, few private schools provide special educational services
for the handicapped, while public schools are required to do so by law. Average
costs of education for each special education student have been estimated to be
almost 2.5 times the average cost for the non‑handicapped student
(Chaikind, Danielson, and Brauen 1993). In New York City it was estimated that
the cost was four times that of regular students in 1993 (Lankford and Wyckoff
1996: 231). Moreover, special education students represent about 12 percent of
all students nationally, but are concentrated almost completely in public
schools (with the exception of those in very high‑cost, specialized
private schools mainly subsidized by government).
Further,
the comparison of average per‑pupil expenditures for public schools
includes other services not provided by private schools. For example, most
private secondary schools do not provide vocational education, a course of
study which varies from two to more than five times the cost of regular
education, depending upon the specialization (Hu and Stromsdorfer 1979).
Transportation services and food services are included in the total for public
school expenditures, but private schools normally charge extra fees for these
services. Finally, the tuition charges that are usually compared with public
school expenditures are those for elementary schools (typically parochial,
Catholic schools), while the public school figures comprise both elementary
schools and the more costly secondary schools.
To
test the assertion that the Milwaukee voucher schools had a per‑pupil
cost that was half of that of comparable public schools, I contacted the
Milwaukee Public Schools to obtain per‑pupil expenditure breakdowns
(Haselow 1996). Voucher schools were receiving $ 4,373 per student in 1996‑97.
The Milwaukee Public Schools had an estimated budget for the same year of $
7,628 per student, but this amount included many services not required or
provided by the voucher schools. For example, the voucher students were
enrolled in kindergarten to eighth grade schools, while the Milwaukee Public
Schools total included the more expensive high school students as well. Voucher
schools did not enroll expensive special education students and did not provide
vocational education, transportation or the extensive food and health services
provided by the Milwaukee Public Schools.
A
more appropriate comparison is to compare site‑based expenditures in
Milwaukee Public Schools with the voucher schools. Milwaukee provides such
school‑based allocations according to pre‑determined personnel
ratios and other factors. (Secondary schools and middle schools have the
largest allocation per student, about $3,815 for each middle school student and
$ 3,635 for each high school student.) The Milwaukee Public Schools budgeted $
3,469 per student in K‑8 schools and $ 3,042 per student in elementary
schools. If we compare the voucher with the per‑pupil amount for K‑8
schools, the voucher schools received about $ 1,000 more per student than the
comparable Milwaukee Public Schools for the 1996‑97 school year. On the
basis of costing experience for public schools, it is estimated that facilities
costs on an annualized basis are about 10 percent of total expenditures in what
is a labor‑intensive enterprise, closing about half of the gap, but still
favoring the voucher schools. The most reasonable conclusion is that voucher
schools in Milwaukee are receiving at least comparable allocations per student
to those of the Milwaukee Public Schools, once the service mix is accounted
for.
Of
course, this raises the question of what accounts for the other costs of the
school district that are not allocated specifically to the individual school
sites. The costs of special education services are budgeted at the central
level; with over 12 percent of the students in these categories and excess
costs averaging about 150 percent more than regular education, this accounts
for almost $1,400 per student when averaged among all students. Transportation
costs including those for carrying students to voucher schools, which are paid
by the district, average about $565 averaged across all the students of the
district, and much more per transported student. In addition, there are the
higher costs of secondary schools, food services, health services, and capital
costs. Overall costs of central office administration are only about 3 percent
of per‑student expenditures. While this does not constitute a precise
cost‑accounting for the two sets of schools, it appears that the costs of
similar services at the school site may actually be higher at the Milwaukee
voucher schools, although the most prudent conclusion at this level of detail
is to suggest that they are comparable. Claims that the public schools cost
twice as much as comparable private schools in other settings should also be
subjected to careful scrutiny. My guess is that such cost comparisons would
show that even in the least efficient school districts, costs for similar
services are not found to be even close to the two‑fold figure that is
commonly cited.
Cost
of a Voucher System
A
shift from the prevalent system of state finance and governance of education to
one based upon educational vouchers will require a profound transformation of
institutions required to support the schooling system. In particular, it will
require far more transaction costs as states must deal with individual schools
and students rather than districts. For example, in California a system of
vouchers would require state authorities to keep records and administer
vouchers to almost 6,000,000 youngsters in place of dealing with about 1,000
local school districts. In order to assure adequate access to alternatives, it
is probable that information centers would need to be established to enable
parents to make informed choices, and an expanded system of publicly funded
transportation would need to be incorporated. In addition, some type of system
of adjudication would need to be provided for parents who wanted a partial
refund of vouchers in order to change schools during the academic year.
Finally, a state system of monitoring and assessment would be needed to establish
voucher eligibility of both students and schools.
The
estimation of the costs of a voucher system to replace existing systems of
schooling cannot be done without specification of the particular voucher plan
that is being considered; the system that it will replace; the setting where it
will be applied; and assumptions about the behavior of schools and families
under the voucher approach. Cyrus Driver and I (Levin and Driver, 1996; Levin
and Driver, forthcoming) have attempted to address these issues and to estimate
illustrative costs in five areas associated with a voucher system. These
include: (1) accommodating additional students; (2) record keeping and
monitoring; (3) transportation; (4) information; and (5) adjudication of
disputes.
Only
a summary of results will be shown here, so the two source documents should be
reviewed for the details underlying the calculations. Cost estimates are
generally for 1995 with a few exceptions.
(1)
Accommodating Additional Students
If
all private school students were to participate with the full range of services
provided by the public schools at the average per‑pupil expenditure
nationally, the added cost would be about $ 33 billion annually. If only 75
percent would be eligible because some schools would not wish to participate in
a plan with government oversight, the cost would be almost $ 25 billion
annually. Or, if the voucher were set at 80 percent of public school costs
because existing private school students are less likely to need services for
special education, compensatory education, bilingual education and so on, these
amounts would be about $ 26 billion for all existing private school students
and $ 20 billion for a 75 percent transfer rate into the voucher system.
(2)
Record‑Keeping and Monitoring
A
voucher system will require extensive record keeping and monitoring systems for
several reasons. First, every child required to be in school under compulsory
attendance laws and those continuing their education through high school
graduation will need to be monitored to ensure that they are in a school
approved to use the voucher. Second, children with different educational needs
will be eligible for different vouchers (e.g. students at each level of
schooling, handicapped students, disadvantaged students, language minority
students). Students will need to be evaluated in terms of needed services and
the appropriate magnitude of the voucher. Third, only schools that meet
³approval² standards will redeem vouchers, so schools must be evaluated,
certified, and monitored for eligibility. (In 1995‑96 two of the
Milwaukee voucher schools closed in mid‑year, stranding the students and
relegating their involuntary return to the Milwaukee Public Schools. At the
time of the writing of this article, criminal charges were pending because of
alleged financial manipulations by the schools¹ operators.) The costs of
monitoring and accreditation would be likely to be particularly high because we
would expect about twice as many schools under a voucher plan, given that
private schools tend to be about half the average size of existing public
schools (Chambers 1981). Using the social security system as an analogy, it was
estimated that even with cost savings from dismantling the present system,
there would be a net additional cost for record‑keeping and monitoring of
about $ 2.5 billion nationally. This figure does not include the costs of
accrediting for eligibility and monitoring the approximately 200,000 schools we
would expect under a market approach, a serious omission and understatement of
costs, because we lacked an analogous data base that might be used for such
cost estimation.
(3)
Transportation
Transportation
costs would be expected to be higher under a voucher system than the present
system for two reasons. First, the advent of choice should lead to more
students attending schools outside of their immediate neighborhoods. Second,
the routes are likely to be of lower density and regularity in terms of pickups
and deliveries. About 60 percent of U.S. public school students are bussed at
present, and we assumed that this would rise to about 80 percent of public and
private school students. After scrutinizing a large number of travel modes and
examining existing costs for school transportation, we estimated that additional
transportation costs would be about $ 42 billion based upon an additional 13.3
million students being bussed and a rise in costs from about $ 415 per student
in 1992‑93 to about $ 1,500 per student. It should be noted that bussing
costs for desegregation purposes in the St. Louis area are at a level of about
$ 2,000 per student per year, a level that was also reported by Milwaukee for
its interdistrict bussing program (Haselow 1996). It should also be noted that
a telephone survey of private schools in New York found transportation fees to
be in this range and higher, with such transport often undertaken through
competitive bidding by private firms. And the use of smaller buses and larger
catchment areas is even more costly as evidenced by both commercial cost
estimates and the experiences in transporting children needing special
education.
(4)
Information Costs
In
order to make informed choices, parents need information on alternatives. At a
minimum, families need to know what choices are available and the
appropriateness of particular choices for their children. They also need
information on such matters as school philosophy, curriculum, personnel,
facilities, test scores, student placements after graduation, registered
complains and their nature, and turnover rates among students. Using a very
modest approach such as one used for a choice program in Massachusetts, we
estimated the per pupil cost at about $ 38 per year or about $ 1.8 billion
nationally. It should be noted that this probably understates seriously the
cost for a highly effective information system that would engage the poor,
minorities and immigrants, groups that have been least likely to participate in
choice systems, but we do not have a knowledge base for estimating the cost of
a more ambitious system.
(5)
Costs of Adjudication
Some
families will choose schools that they later find are inappropriate for their
students. Schools may also wish to suspend or discharge students who do not
meet certain standards. In cases like these there may be issues of due process
as well as the right of a student to obtain an additional partial‑voucher
to use for another school if the original one has been redeemed. There may also
be conflicts about whether a student is getting an appropriate voucher for the
educational services that the family believes are required and other challenges
to the voucher agency. In all of these cases a means of adjudication must be
available to quickly resolve the dilemma so that a child¹s education is not
seriously interrupted. Using cost data from mediation and due process hearings
for special education and assuming that only 1 percent of students will require
adjudication in any given year, we estimate the costs of adjudication at about
$ 1.8 billion.
Total
Costs of a Voucher System
These
are first estimates of public costs of a voucher system, and they total almost
$ 73 billion, about $ 1,500 per student or an additional 25 percent of the
public educational budget nationally under a mid‑range set of assumptions
(Levin and Driver, forthcoming). Well over half of this represents a shift in
the cost burden from the private to the public sector rather than higher social
costs. For example, accommodating present private school students with vouchers
and transportation of existing private school students who are presently
transported represents a shift, not a higher cost. The net costs of record‑keeping
and monitoring may be slightly over‑stated if we have not fully accounted
for the savings from existing practices, but this category of costs accounted
for less than 4 percent of the total. Information costs are surely too low, and
we have not included, at all, the costs of accrediting and monitoring schools
to be eligible to redeem vouchers. We conclude that the shift from the existing
system to a voucher system with a well‑functioning school marketplace in
which adequate transportation and information is provided will demand
considerable additional public resources for education beyond those that will
need to be allocated for educational vouchers and instructional services.
POSTSCRIPT
During
the last five years we have come a long way in acquiring evidence that is
pertinent to the consideration of educational vouchers, although there are
still many gaps in our knowledge base. Unfortunately, policy debates on
vouchers are largely devoid of references to the available evidence or are
limited to citing only a ³favored² study that supports a particular
perspective. I have suggested here that there is a considerable consensus
arising from the available corpus of evidence on the first two issues set out
in this paper, and at least a first approximation on the cost issues. I want to
conclude by stating that nothing in this paper should give much comfort to
those who might wish to defend the status quo. In my view, considerable gains
in educational efficiency are possible, whether vouchers are the answer or some
other type of system reform. Evidence of this claim can be found in a school
reform movement that has extended to about 1,000 public, Catholic, and charter
schools in some 40 states, where we have demonstrated that substantial
improvements in educational results can be obtained (Levin forthcoming).
REFERENCES
Ambler,
John S. (1994) ³Who Benefits from Educational Choice? Some Evidence from
Europe,² Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, Vol. 13, No. 3, pp. 454‑476.
Alexander,
Karl L. and Aaron Pallas (1985) ³School Sector and Cognitive Performance: When
is a Little a Little? Sociology of Education, Vol. 58, pp. 115‑128.
American
Enterprise Institute (1978) Tuition Tax Credits and Alternatives (Washington,
D.C.: American Enterprise Institute).
Archbald,
Douglas (1988) Magnet Schools, Voluntary Desegregation, and Public Choice
Theory: Limits and Possibilities in a Big City School System (Madison, WI:
School of Education, University of Wisconsin‑Madison).
Arnott,
R. and J. Rowse (1987) ³Peer Group Effects and Educational Attainment,² Journal
of Public Economics, Vol. 32, pp. 287‑305.
Bartell,
Ernest S.J. (1968) Costs and Benefits of Catholic Elementary and Secondary
Schools. (Notre Dame IN: Notre Dame Press).
Boaz,
David and R. Morris Barrett (1996) What Would a School Voucher Buy? The Real
Cost of Private Schools, Cato Briefing Paper # 25 (Washington, D.C.: The CATO
Institute).
Chambers,
Jay G. (1981) ³An Analysis of School Size Under a Voucher System,² Educational
Evaluation and Policy Analysis, Vol. 3, pp. 29‑40.
Coleman,
James S. (1988) ³Social Capital in the Creation of Human Capital,² American
Journal of Sociology , Vol. 94, Supplement: pp. 95‑120.
Coleman,
James S., Thomas Hoffer, and Sally Kilgore (1982) High School Achievement:
Public, Catholic, and Private Schools (New York: Basic Books).
Dreeben,
Robert and Adam Gamoran (1986) ³Race, Instruction, and Learning,² American
Sociological Review, Vol. 51, pp. 660‑669.
Dynarski,
Mark, R. Schwab, and E. Zampelli (1989) ³Local Characteristics and Public
Production: The Case of Education,² Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 26, pp.
250‑263.
Echols, Frank H. and J. Douglas Willms
(1995) ³Reasons for School Choice in Scotland,² Journal of Educational Policy,
Vol. 10, No. 2, pp. 143‑156.
Evans,
William N., Wallace E. Oates, and Robert M. Schwab (1992) ³Measuring Peer Group
Effects: A Study of Teenage Behavior,² Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 100,
No. 5, pp. Pp. 996‑991.
Evans,
William N., and Robert M. Schwab (1993) ³Finishing High School and Starting
College: Do Catholic Schools Make a Difference?² Department of Economics,
University of Maryland.
Friedman,
Milton (1955) ³The Role of Government in Education,² In R. A. Solo (ed.)
Economics and the Public Interest (New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University
Press).
(1962)
³The Role of Government in Education,² In Capitalism and Freedom (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press), Chap. VI.
Gamoran,
Adam (1991) ³Schooling and Achievement: Additive Versus Interactive Models,² In
Steve W. Raudenbush and J. Douglas Willms (ed), Schools, Classrooms, and
Pupils:International Studies of Schooling from a Multilevel Perspective (San
Diego: Academic Press), pp. 37‑51.
(1996)
³Student Achievement in Public Magnet, Public Comprehensive, and Private City
High Schools,² Educational Evaluation and Policy Analysis, Vol. 18, No. 1
(Spring), pp. 1‑18.
_____________
and M. Nystrand (1994) ³Tracking, Instruction, and Achievement,² International
Journal of Educational Research, Vol. 21, No. 5, pp. 217‑231.
Goldberger,
Arthur S. and Glen G. Cain (1982) ³The Causal Outcomes in the Coleman, Hoffer
and Kilgore Report,² Sociology of Education, Vol. 55, pp. 103‑122.
Greene,
Jay P., Paul E. Peterson, and Jiangtao Du (1996), ³The Effectiveness of School
Choice in Milwaukee: A Secondary Analysis of Data from the Program¹s
Evaluation,² Paper presented at Annual Meetings of the American Political Science
Association, San Francisco (August 30).
Gutmann,
Amy (1987) Democratic Education(Princeton: Princeton University Press).
Haertel, Edward H., Thomas James, and Henry M. Levin, eds. (1987) Comparing
Public and Private Schools: School Achievement, Vol 2 (New York: The Falmer
Press).
Haselow,
Douglas (1996) ³Responses to Letter from H. M. Levin, November 20, 1996²
Milwaukee Public Schools. Hoffer, Thomas, Andrew Greeley, and James S. Coleman
(1985) ³Achievement Growth in Public and Catholic Schools,² Sociology of
Education, Vol. 58, pp. 74‑97.
Hoxby,
Caroline Minter (1996) ³The Effects of Private School Vouchers on Schools and
Students,² in Helen F. Ladd (Ed.), Holding Schools Accountable (Washington,
D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1996), pp. 177‑208.
Inkeles,
Alex (1966) ³Social Structure and the Socialization of Competence,² Harvard
Educational Review, Vol. 36, pp. 265‑283.
Kane,
Thomas J. (1996) ³Comments on Chapters Five and Six,² in Helen F. Ladd (Ed.),
Holding Schools Accountable (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution), pp.
209‑217.
Lankford,
Hamilton and James Wyckoff, ³The Allocation of Resources to Special Education
and Regular Instruction,² in Helen F. Ladd (ed.), Holding Schools Accountable
(Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1996), pp. 221‑257.
Lee,
Valerie E., Robert G. Croninger, and Julia B. Smith (1996) ³Equity and Choice
in Detroit,² In Bruce Fuller and Richard F. Elmore (eds), Who Chooses? Who
Loses? (New York: Teachers College, 1996), pp. 70‑91.
Levin,
Henry M. (1968) ³The Failure of the Public Schools and the Free Market Remedy,²
The Urban Review, Vol. 2, pp. 32‑37.
_____________
(1980) ³Educational Vouchers and Social Policy,² In Care and Education of Young
Children in America, Ron Haskins and James Gallagher (eds) (Norwood, NJ: Ablex
Publishing Col, 1980).
_____________
(1987) ³Education as a Public and Private Good,² Journal of Policy Analysis and
Management, Vol. 6, pp. 628‑641.
_____________
(1991) ³The Economics of Educational Choice,² Economics of Education Review,
Vol. 10, No. 2, pp. 137‑158.
_____________
(forthcoming) ³Raising School Productivity: An X‑Efficiency Approach,²
Economics of Education Review (forthcoming).
_____________
and Cyrus E. Driver (1996) ³Estimating the Costs of an Educational Voucher
System,² In William J. Fowler, Jr. (ed) Selected Papers in School Finance 1994,
NCES 96‑068 (Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Education, National
Center for Educational Statistics), pp. 63‑88.
_____________
and _____________ (forthcoming) ³Costs of an Educational Voucher System,²
Educational Economics. Available in pre‑publication form from authors,
CERAS 109, Stanford University, Stanford, CA 94305‑3084.
Link,
Charles and James Mulligan (1991) ³Classmates¹ Effects on Black Student
Achievement in Public School Classrooms,² Economics of Education Review, Vol.
10, pp. 297‑310.
Martinez,
Valerie, Kenneth Godwin, and Frank R. Kemerer (1996) ³Public School Choice in
San Antonio: Who Chooses and with What Effects?² In Bruce Fuller and Richard
Elmore (eds), Who Chooses? Who Loses? (New York: Teachers College Press), pp.50‑69.
Moe,
Terry M. (1995a) Private Vouchers (Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press).
___________ (1995b) ³Private Vouchers,² in Terry M. Moe (ED), Private Vouchers
(Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press), pp. 1‑40.
Moore,
Donald and Susan Davenport (1990) ³School Choice: The New School Sorting
Machine,² In William Boyd and Herbert Walberg (eds) Choice in Education:
Potential and Problems (Berkeley, CA: McCutcheon Publishing Co.), pp. 187‑224.
Murnane,
Richard (1986) ³Comparisons of Private and Public Schools: The Critical Role of
Regulations,² in Daniel Levy (ed.), Private Education: Studies in Choice and
Public Policy (New York: Oxford University Press).
Neal,
Deal (1995) ³The Effect of Catholic Secondary Schooling on Educational
Attainment,² NBER Working Paper Series, Working Paper 5353 (Cambridge, MA.:
National Bureau of Economic Research).
Nechyba,
Thomas (1996) ³Public School Finance in a General Equilibrium Tiebout World:
Equalization Programs, Peer Effects and Private School Vouchers,² (Department
of Economics, Stanford University).
Alan
Peshkin (1986) God¹s Choice: The Total Fundamentalist Christian School
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press).
Peterson,
Paul E and Chad Noyes (1996) ³Under Extreme Duress, School Choice Success,²
Occasional Paper 96‑1, Program in Education Policy and Governance
(Cambridge, MA: Harvard University).
Rubenstein,
M., R. Hamar, and Nancy Adelman (1992) Minnesota¹s Open Enrollment Option, U.S.
Department of Education Contract No. 89089001, (Washington, DC: Policy Studies
Associates).
Shavit,
Yehuda and R. A. Williams (1985) ³Ability Grouping and Contextual Determinants
of Educational Expectations in Israel,² American Sociological Review, Vol. 50,
pp. 62‑73.
Summers,
Anita and Roberta Wolfe (1977) ³Do Schools Make a Difference?² American
Economic Review, pp. 639‑652.
Rumberger,
Russell and Katherine A. Larson (1996) ³The Impact of Student Mobility on High
School Completion², Paper presented at Annual Meetings of the American
Educational Research Association, New York, (April).
_______________
and J. Douglas Willms (1992) ³The Impact of Racial and Ethnic Segregation on
the Achievement Gap in California High Schools, Educational Evaluation and
Policy Analysis, Vol. 14, No. 4, pp. 377‑396.
Torney‑Purta,
Judith (1984) ³Political Socialization and Policy: The United States in a Cross‑Cultural
Context,² In H. Stevenson and A. Siegel (eds), Child Development Research and
Social Policy (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).
Vandenberghe,
Vincent (1996) Functioning and Regulation of Educational Quasi‑Markets,
Nouvelle serie‑No. 283 (Louvain‑la Neuve, Belgium: Faculte Des
Sciences Economiques, Sociales Et Politiques, Universite Catholique de
Louvain).
West,
Edwin G. (1981) The Economics of Educational Tax Credits (Washington, D.C.: The
Heritage Foundation). Willms, J. Douglas (1983) ³Do Private Schools Produce
Higher Levels of Academic Achievement? New Evidence for the Tuition Tax Credit
Debate,² In Tom James and Henry M. Levin (ed.), Public Dollars for Private
Schools (Philadelphia, PA: Temple University Press).
_________________
(1985) ³Catholic School Effects on Academic Achievement: New Evidence from the
High School and Beyond Follow‑up Study,² Sociology of Education, Vol. 58,
pp. 98‑114.
________________
(1986) ³Social Class Segregation and Its Relationship to Pupils¹ Examination
Results in Scotland,² American Sociological Review, Vol. 51, pp. 224‑241.
________________ (1996) ³School Choice
and Community Segregation: Findings from Scotland,² in Alan C. Kerckhoff (ed.)
Generating Social Stratification: Toward a New Research Agenda (Boulder, CO:
Westview Press).
________________
and Frank Echols (1992) ³Alert and Inert Clients: The Scottish Experience of
Parental Choice of Schools,² Economics of Education Review, Vol. 11, No. 4, pp.
339‑350.
Witte,
John F. (1997) ³Achievement Effects of the Milwaukee Voucher Program,² Paper
presented at the 1997 Annual Meetings of the American Economic Association (New
Orleans: January 4).
___________
(1992) ³Private School Versus Public School Achievement: Are There Findings
That Should Affect the Educational Choice Debate,² Economics of Education
Review, Vol. 11, pp. 371‑394.
Witte,
John F., Christopher A. Thorn, Kim M. Pritchard, and Michelle Claibourne (1994)
The Fourth Year Report: The Milwaukee Parental Choice Program. (Madison, WI:
Wisconsin Department of Public Instruction).
Witte,
John F. and Christopher A. Thorn (1996) ³Who Chooses? Voucher and Interdistrict
Choice Programs in Milwaukee,² American Journal of Education, Vol. 104, pp. 186‑217.
Witte,
John F., Troy D. Sterr, and Christopher A. Thorn (1995) Fifth Year Report:
Milwaukee Parental Choice Program, (Madison, WI: Robert M. La Follette
Institute of Public Affairs, University of Wisconsin—Madison). December
1996
Copyright
1996. Readers may redistribute this article to other individuals for
noncommercial use, provided that the text and this notice remain intact. This
article may not be resold, reprinted, or redistributed for compensation of any
kind without prior written permission from the author.